Household savings rate: going up, or down?
2019/01/15
Declining trend of household savings rate
Japanese household savings rate used to be very high: at its peak in mid-1970s, it was about 23 percent of household disposable income. Explaining the high Japanese savings rate was one of the most popular topics for an economics paper.
However, since then, it has gradually fallen: if fell below 10 percent in FY2000, and it even turned negative (-0.9 percent) in FY2013. It was expected that the savings rate of the household will keep on declining (for the reasons to be mentioned below), and, from savings-and-investment-balance reasons, the current account surplus that Japan had almost continuously since late 1960s will eventually turn deficit.
Trend has reversed since FY 2013
The performance of the Japanese economy since FY2014 have rejected that kind of forecasts. The national account figures for FY2017, which was published in December 25 last year, revealed that household savings rate has been rising since FY2013 to reach 2.3 percent in FY2017 (Figure 1).
Figure 1: Household Savings Rate
Net lending by the domestic sectors to overseas, which is almost equivalent to current account surplus in the balance of payments statistics, has risen to 4.1 percent of GDP, the largest surplus in ten years (Figure 2).
Figure 2: Net lending by Domestic Sectors
Reasons for the temporary reversal
Why did the forecasts on household savings rate turn out to be wrong?
The long-term declining trend witnessed until FY2013 was the result of the aging of the population in Japan. Life-cycle hypothesis tells us that elderlies are dis-savers so that when their share in the population rises, the savings rate for the total households would fall. If that is true, since the aging process is still proceeding, household savings rate should continue to fall even after FY2014.
Even though that is the basic trend, there seems to be some special factors at play after FY2014 which made the declining trend less obvious.
First is the temporary impact of the consumption tax rate hike that took place in April 2014. Since retail prices inclusive of consumption tax are going to rise, consumers brought forward their purchases, especially of expensive and durable goods, which otherwise should have taken place after April. The result was a surge in consumption before April (which means it took place in FY2013), and a drop of consumption after April (which means it took place in FY2014). It implies that, given the level of disposable income, savings should have fallen in FY 2013 and risen in FY2014, which coincides with the observation.
Second is the consequences of an increase in precautionary savings. Because of the slowdown of the economy in response to the consumption tax rate hike, consumers faced increasing uncertainty about the future of the economy. It is reflected in the consumer confidence index which shows a deterioration in the index in FY2014, limited it may be compared to the post-Lehman shock drop (Figure 3).
Figure 3: Consumer Confidence Index
It seems to have led to a tightening of spending and building up of savings by the households. Similar reaction by the households that led to a rise in their savings rate also seemed to have taken place after the Lehman shock of 2008, albeit at a larger magnitude.
One thing worth mentioning in passing is the substitutability between household savings and corporate savings. The theory on substitutability between household and corporate savings, which is based on a assumption that households are the ultimate holders of companies, implies that, when household savings rises, corporate savings should fall.
While the reality in Japan that households do not hold so much of corporate shares rejects the assumption behind the theory, Figure 3 suggests that there may be such a substitutability. In fact, correlation coefficient between the savings for period FY1994-FY2017 is 0.9052.
Since the household savings rate has been rising in the recent years, if the substitutability theory holds, it should be accompanied by a falling corporate savings. However, the fact is that corporate savings continued to rise during the period (Figure 4).
Figure 4: Household and Corporate Savings
Reasons for the absence of a declining trend in current account surplus
Why is it, then, that there is no declining trend for net lending by domestic sectors to overseas (i.e. current account surplus), as Figure 2 shows.
When household saving rate falls, net borrowing by the overseas sector will also fall when (a) domestic savings as a whole also falls, while (b) domestic investment remains the same.
The data on domestic savings do show a falling trend (Figure 5). While the fall in household savings is somewhat offset by the rise in corporate savings, negative savings by the general government contributed to the fall in domestic savings.
However, domestic investment did not remain the same; rather, it fell. It explains why the net lending by the domestic sector does not show a falling trend.
Figure 5: Domestic Savings, Domestic Investment, and Net Lending
The parallel fall in domestic savings and domestic investment reminds us of the Feldstein-Horioka Paradox; findings that domestic investment is constrained by the domestic savings, suggesting that globalization is still limited in terms of mobilizing foreign savings in Japan. It is consistent with the observation that inward foreign direct investment is limited in Japan throughout Japan.
Important implication for fiscal consolidation
Whether household saving rate is going to fall again, and whether current account surplus is going to vanish is an issue which has important implications for policies. In particular, for a country like Japan with high government debt, it is of vital importance whether we have to depend more on foreign savings or not. The earlier current account turns into deficit, the quicker we need to achieve fiscal consolidation. The development of household savings will need a closer scrutiny.
- 2023/11/22
-
Japan’s Monetary Policy as Seen from Its “Level” and from Its “Direction”
- 2023/10/17
-
History of Shunto and Its Economic Significance
- 2023/09/21
-
Isn’t Deflation Over Yet?
- 2023/08/18
-
What the GDP Figures for 2023 Q2 Tell Us
- 2023/07/21
-
The Rise in Core CPI and the Outcome of Shunto