Japanese Economy as seen from a Quantity Rationing Model
2018/09/05
Prices and wages that seem to be rigid
In spite of the introduction of an inflation target of 2 percent, and an aggressive monetary easing to achieve the target, prices in Japan have been slow to respond. At the background is the sluggish wage performance: the fall in the unemployment rate to below 3 percent which was perceived to be a full-employment rate apparently has not provided enough pressure for the wages to rise.
These observations give an impression that prices and wages are not playing their role in the Japanese markets. If they are not flexible, the markets will fail to clear, and demand and supply would not match.
Suppose that the prices and wages are actually rigid so that markets do not clear. What will happen in this kind of an economy?
Quantity rationing model and the four regimes
This kind of a problem was exactly what the “disequilibrium macroeconomics,” which was popular in the 1970s, tried to address. It focused on the quantity rationing that may arise in that kind of a situation, and tried to analyze what kind of a macroeconomic equilibrium would be achieved. In this sense, the term “disequilibrium” is not accurate. It is from this reason that I will call this approach in the following as quantity rationing model.
Let me elaborate a little bit on the quantity rationing model. Suppose there are two markets; goods and labor markets. If prices and wages are rigid in their markets, demand and supply would never clear (unless by chance). In such a situation, transactions would satisfy only whichever is shorter (e.g. supply, if supply < demand), and whichever is longer (e.g. demand, if supply< demand) would be subject to quantity rationing. It means that the whichever is longer would find some part of it not being satisfied. If quantity rationing takes place, it is natural to think that the agent subject to rationing would alter its demand or supply in the other market.
Based on such an understanding, we are able to classify the situation in an economy into four regimes, reflecting which of the demand and supply is subject to quantity rationing (Figure 1). (The following is based on Muellbauer and Portes, 1979).
Figure 1: The Four Regimes under Quantity Rationing Model
“Classical unemployment” refers to a regime where households’ labor supply is exceeding firms’ labor demand, so that households are subject to quantity rationing in the labor market (i.e. there is unemployment). At the same time, households’ goods demand is exceeding firms’ product supply so that households are also subject to quantity rationing in the goods market. Such a situation could arise when real wages are too high so that firms cannot increase employment, and as a result, firms cannot supply goods enough to satisfy households’ goods demand.
“Keynesian unemployment” is a regime where households’ labor supply is exceeding firms’ labor demand, so that households are rationed in the labor market (i.e. there is unemployment). On the other hand, firms’ goods supply is exceeding households’ goods demand, so that it is the firms that are rationed in the goods market. This kind of a situation could arise when unemployment in the labor market constraints the goods demand that households can express in the goods market.
“Underconsumption” refers to a regime where firms’ labor demand is exceeding households’ labor supply so that the firms are rationed in the labor market (i.e. there is labor shortage). In addition, firms are also rationed in the goods market because their goods supply is exceeding households’ goods demand. This corresponds to a situation where real wages are so low that households are unwilling to supply labor, and, at the same time, unable to increase their demand for goods.
Finally, “repressed inflation” is a regime where firms’ labor demand is exceeding households’ labor supply so that there is labor shortage in the labor market, while households’ goods demand is exceeding firms’ goods supply so that there is goods shortage in the goods market. In this kind of a situation, both prices and wages should rise if they were flexible. This kind of a situation could arise when households are unable to purchase goods as desired so that there is less incentive for them to supply labor.
Understanding the Japanese economy by the model
Which of the four regimes does the Japanese economy belong to?
Because we observe labor shortage, there should be an excessive demand in the labor market and firms are rationed as a result. Therefore, Japanese economy should be either in “underconsumption” or “repressed inflation.”
If we focus on the output gap that has turned positive, it is possible to think that there is an excess demand in the goods market. If so, then the regime we are in should be “repressed inflation.” However, it seems implausible to think that there is excessive demand in the goods market and that there is goods shortage, especially for households.
It seems more realistic to think that firms are in excessive supply: they wish to find more customers, especially in households, for their goods. If this is true, the Japanese economy should be in “underconsumption” regime.
This puzzle could be solved if we acknowledge the fact that the main thrust behind the current expansionary phase has been exports, not private consumption. If we compare the performance of real GDP with those of real private consumption and real exports, we find that real private consumption has increased much more slowly than real exports (Figure 2). The increase in real GDP and the consequent positive output gap is due mainly to increase in real exports, and not to increase in real private consumption.
Figure 2: GDP, Private Consumption, and Exports
In other words, although it might seem that there is an excess demand in the goods market, it is not the situation for the households: They are facing excess supply in (consumer) goods market.
Policy implications of the “underconsumption” regime
What is the policy implication of identifying the current situation of the Japanese economy as “underconsumption”?
First, it would mean that encouraging wage increase is the most important mean to overcome the current situation.
“Underconsumption,” as we have already seen, is a result of real wages being too low. Therefore, if we raise real wages, labor supply would increase while labor demand would reduce, so that labor shortage will be resolved. In addition, if real wages increase, households’ goods demand should increase, thereby resolving excess supply in the goods market as well.
In order to achieve increase in real wages, policies should give more priority to structural policies in the labor market area.
Second, it would mean that expansionary macroeconomic policies should be used in a careful manner.
Expansionary macroeconomic policies are important as tools to encourage increase in real wages. It would show their maximum effect when they are accompanied by structural policies as mentioned above. If, to the contrary, they are not accompanied by structural policies, expansionary macroeconomic policies would only end up exaggerating the excess demand for labor: they may not succeed in shifting the economy to a more desirable equilibrium despite the use of valuable resources.
Usefulness of the model
Needless to say, prices and wages are not determined exogenously as the quantity rationing model assumes. They should, in the long-run, reflect the demand and supply situation of the markets, and adjust to clear the markets.
However, if prices and wages take time to change and seem almost rigid, we should be able to make use of a quantity rationing model to analyze the economic situation in the short-run as a first order approximation.
It is in this sense that I think it useful to analyze the current situation and think about the policy recommendation using the model.
- 2023/11/22
-
Japan’s Monetary Policy as Seen from Its “Level” and from Its “Direction”
- 2023/10/17
-
History of Shunto and Its Economic Significance
- 2023/09/21
-
Isn’t Deflation Over Yet?
- 2023/08/18
-
What the GDP Figures for 2023 Q2 Tell Us
- 2023/07/21
-
The Rise in Core CPI and the Outcome of Shunto